Pages

Friday, September 27, 2013

At Least the Fed Has An Inflation Target, Right?

Five years into the crisis and the Fed still has not adopted a nominal GDP level target. At least we can take solace in the fact that the Fed now has an explicit inflation target, right? After all, the Fed stated it was serious about its new 2% inflation target when announced in January, 2012:
The inflation rate over the longer run is primarily determined by monetary policy, and hence the Committee has the ability to specify a longer-run goal for inflation. The Committee judges that inflation at the rate of 2 percent, as measured by the annual change in the price index for personal consumption expenditures, is most consistent over the longer run with the Federal Reserve's statutory mandate. Communicating this inflation goal clearly to the public helps keep longer-term inflation expectations firmly anchored, thereby fostering price stability and enhancing the Committee's ability to promote maximum employment in the face of significant economic disturbances.
Now an inflation target can be problematic if there are large and frequent supply shocks, but if we are in a slump that is largely the result of demand shocks this target should be good news. It should hold the Fed's feet to the fire--more so than when it was implicitly targeting inflation--and force it to do all the wonderful things promised in the paragraph above.

So let's see how the Fed has done by its own standard of targeting 2% PCE core inflation:


This is not what the Fed promised with its new inflation target. Instead of gravitating around an average 2% inflation target, the Fed seems to have made 2% an upper bound. And the lower bound appears to be around 1%. This band seems to have been operational since the crisis began. It also appears that the Fed's purchases of treasury securities are closely tied to subsequent changes in the inflation rate as seen below. Maybe the apparent make-it-up-as-we-go-along nature of the QE programs was not so ad-hoc after all. Maybe they always have been tied to keeping PCE core inflation in this band.


Just this week Justin Wolfers noted that the PCE deflator declined this past quarter. He wondered how the Fed could allow this to happen if it had a 2% inflation target. The answer, it seems, is the Fed is targeting an inflation band with 2% as the upper bound.

This is a point Ryan Avent has been making for some time. Here he is back in April, 2012:
The Fed's second failure is to treat the 2% figure as a ceiling rather than a target...The Fed's preferred inflation measure—core PCE inflation—remains below 2%; core PCE was 1.9% year-on-year in February, in which month it increased at a 1.6% annual rate. Inflation expectations have been stable to falling since then.

Perhaps more telling, the Fed gives a range for projected inflation over the next three years with 2% as the upper extent. If the Fed does indeed have a symmetric approach to the target, as Mr Bernanke asserted yesterday, one would expect 2% to be at the middle of the range, not the top. This is particularly damning as the Fed's estimate of the natural rate of unemployment doesn't appear at all in the projected unemployment-rate range over the next three years; the closest the Fed comes to meeting that side of the mandate is in 2014, when the bottom end of the projected unemployment-rate range gets within 0.7 percentage points of the top end of the natural-rate range.

The Fed isn't just failing on the guideposts set by economists like Paul Krugman, Kenneth Rogoff, Greg Mankiw and, yes, Ben Bernanke. It's failing on the terms it sets for itself. Consistently.
So exactly what has changed with the Fed's new inflation target? Other than creating more confusion, nothing. And the Fed seems to be getting really good at creating confusion as evidenced by the no taper fiasco. This has to stop. We need monetary policy that will respond in a predictable, systematic way conditional on the state of the economy. Right now the Fed is not doing that.

4 comments:

  1. "The answer, it seems, is the Fed is targeting an inflation band with 2% as the upper bound."

    The FOMC's projections are amazingly accurate...provided one only looks at their core inflation forecasts.

    Consider their June projections from 2009, 2010, 2011 and 2012. Their mean error (not mean absolute error), with respect to the central tendency of their projection, for core PCEPI is +0.04 points for the same year, +0.12 points for one year out and +0.08 points for two years out.

    Since the Fed is the institution legally mandated with attaining low inflation and maximum employment the FOMC's forecasts are really targets, since if they're not forecasting their target, they're obviously forecasting failure. And since their core inflation forecast record has been stellar, that's obviously the thing they really care about.

    Incidentally the central tendency of their June 2013 projections are for year on year core PCEPI to be 1.25% in 2013Q4, 1.65% in 2014Q4 and 1.85% in 2015Q4. The average three year out forecast for core PCEPI over the June projections made from 2009 to 2013 is 1.58%.

    ReplyDelete
  2. I agree..the inflation target of 2 percent is seen as a ceiling, and therefore any inflation above 1.5 percent turns the FOMC into a bunch of weaklings...so the real target is then 1.5 percent...the problem with that is at 1.5 percent inflation any economic weakness drives down inflation and interest rates, and you get close to or in ZLB....

    I still do not know when 2 percent became sacred, and also really a ceiling. Does anyone know if 3 percent would result in a little more flexibility and more robust real growth?

    ReplyDelete
  3. The problem is that prior to the housing bubble pop (2004-2007), the Fed was terribly wrong in feeding the bubble with slightly too loose 2.1, 2.2% inflation -- just when they should have had tighter anti-asset bubble policies. Now, after the correction, they are failing to provide the money that businesses need to expand workforces.

    Of course, no amount of money from the Fed to banks who buy gov't bonds but fail to loan out the money to business will really stimulate the business expansion that is needed for reducing unemployment.

    Where are the graphs of bank money lent for housing, bank money lent for small business, bank money lent to big business? Tight / Loose money in practice should really be based on the ease of small companies getting bank money loans.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Tom, another way of saying this is that the broad (inside) money supply has been deficient. I agree and hold that Fed could indirectly affect this through better signalling and intentions (e.g. commitment to a level target).

      Delete